スコットランドリーグ放送

<ウェブサイト名>

<現在の時刻>

出典: 標準

This page uses Javascript. Please enable Javascript in your browser. Skip to Content Japanese English Chinese About RIETI Site Map Help Contact Discussion Papers Search Site Search Menu Research Areas Research Programs (FY2024-2028) Research Programs (FY2020-2023) Research Programs (FY2016-2019) Research Programs (FY2011-2015) Policy Research Domains (FY2006-2010) Projects Survey Fellows According to Title Alphabetical order RIETI Alumni Research/Policy Papers Discussion Papers (English) Discussion Papers (Japanese) Policy Discussion Papers (English) Policy Discussion Papers (Japanese) Technical Papers (English) Technical Papers (Japanese) Non Technical Summaries List of Articles in Journals Research Digest Discussion Papers Search Publications RIETI Books (English) RIETI Books (Japanese) History of Japan's Trade and Industry Policy Authors' Words Other Publications (English) Other Publications (Japanese) Events Symposiums Workshops BBL Seminars Archived Seminar Series Data JIP Database R-JIP Database CIP Database Industry-Specific Nominal and Real Effective Exchange Rates AMU and AMU Deviation Indicators JSTAR RIETI-TID RIETI FDI Database ICPA Project Links Articles Column Special Series Newspapers & Magazines Fellows' Works VoxEU Column From IZA Perspectives from Around the World Other Contents RIETI Report Policy Update Keizai Sangyo Journal (METI Journal) Research Areas Fellows Research/Policy Papers Publications Events Data Articles Site Map Technical Issues Coontact Discussion Papers Search Close HomeArticlesPerspectives from Around the World Perspectives from Around the World 165 The political cost of reforms Tweet Print Chris PAPAGEORGIOU Chief of the Development Macroeconomics Division in the Research Department, International Monetary Fund (IMF) For Chris PAPAGEORGIOU's full bio,https://www.imf.org/external/np/cv/AuthorCV.aspx?AuthID=172 "It ought to be remembered that there is nothing more difficult to take in hand, more perilous to conduct, or more uncertain in its success, than to take the lead in the introduction of a new order of things. Because the innovator has for enemies all those who have done well under the old conditions, and lukewarm defenders in those who may do well under the new." Niccolò Machiavelli (1505). Policies that change the way governments work—known as structural reforms—range from reducing regulatory barriers to competition and opening to trade and financial flows to increasing labor market flexibility. They are motivated by objectives that include increasing productivity, investment, and employment, and making the economy more resilient to shocks (Ostry et al., 2008; Prati et al., 2013; Quinn and Toyoda, 2008). While there has been broad agreement on the economic benefits of structural reforms, the political impact is less settled. This is because reforms may generate gains for society as a whole only in the longer term, while inflicting short-term pains on some sectors. Those affected may be highly vocal and well organized. When this happens, politicians may hold back on reforms for fear they will be penalized at the ballot box. Economic reforms are often painful in the short term and hence unpopular, but does that mean reform-minded leaders always pay a price at the ballot box? Alesina, Furceri, Ostry, Papageorgiou and Quinn (2020) in their analysis of structural reforms and election outcomes in 66 countries suggest that this is not necessarily true. In this work we explore the electoral consequences of structural reforms through the prism of two new databases. One measures reforms in domestic finance, external finance, trade, product and labor markets, covering 90 advanced and developing economies, from 1973 to 2014. The other chronicles the timing and results of national elections. Figure 1. Structural Reform Indices for 90 Advanced and Developing Economies The question is timely, because the economic policy agenda in both advanced and developing economies is increasingly focused on structural reforms, amid persistently weak medium-term growth and limited fiscal space in many countries. There is a pressing need and strong case for well-designed, appropriately timed, and carefully implemented structural reforms. This is especially true in emerging market economies and developing economies, where deregulation has stalled in recent years. A major push for structural reform would mean significant output gains in the medium term in both advanced and developing economies as confirmed by our own research (Figure 2). Figure 2. Macroeconomic Effects of Reform—output Effect (%) Note: Output effects estimated using equation (1). t= 0 is the year of the reform; solid lines denote the response of output to a major reform event, defined as a change of two standard deviations in the reform indicator. Dotted lines denote 95 percent confidence bands. The question which then remains is: granted reforms are economically significant, but at what political cost? Our new research suggests that electoral costs associated with structural reforms can be avoided, or at least substantially lessened, if political considerations are factored into policy design. Our key finding is that reforms do not always mean political risk. Specifically, based on a panel of 66 democratic countries we show that while on average reforms are associated with electoral costs, specific effects depend not only on the type of reform, but also on when in the electoral cycle it is implemented. Reforms are shown to be benign or even favorable politically when implemented swiftly after elections so that governments can reap the rewards from the medium-term economic gains. Electoral risks are heightened when governments delay and enact reforms on the eve of an election, given that short-term dislocation effects are often caused by reforms. Figure 3. Macroeconomic Effects of Reform Depending on Economic Conditions (%) Note: Output effects estimated using equation (2). t= 0 is the year of the reform; solid blue lines denote the response of output to a major reform event, defined as a change of two standard deviations in the reform indicator, in recessions and expansions. Solid black lines denote the unconditional effects reported in Figure 3. Dotted lines denote 95 percent confidence bands. Finally, not all reforms are equal from an electoral perspective. The data suggest that those that engender increased income inequality—notably financial sector deregulation (such as banking sector privatization and removing controls on credit and interest rates) and opening to financial flows under some conditions—can exact a higher cost at election time (see, e.g. de Han and Sturm, 2017; Furceri and Loungani, 2018; Ostry et al., 2018). There are three key takeaways from our analysis. First, governments should act swiftly following an electoral victory to carry out reforms during their political honeymoon period. Second, reforms are best implemented when economic conditions are favorable. Third, policymakers should factor in any harm reforms may have on income distribution and take well-communicated upfront steps to offset such side effects. These takeaways are consistent with evidence that the benefits of reforms take time to materialize—often beyond the electoral term—and with the notion that voters do not internalize the lag between the implementation of a reform and its economic effects. Voters seem to attribute the state of the economy at a point in time at least in part to reforms implemented around that time. The cost of liberalizing reforms during recessions is especially large when they occur in an election year. When reforms occur during expansions, voters do not punish and may even reward the incumbent. Our findings are also consistent with voters facing a signal extraction problem regarding the competence of leaders. Growth benefits from reforms are years in the making, and voters appear not to anticipate these future benefits. In downturns, voters appear to struggle to correctly attribute how much of the downturn is due to the policymaker's policies and how much is due to the general state of the economy. Even when successful economically, reforms can have a clear contractionary impact on a subset of the population. Our results appear consistent with both voter myopia and rational behavior by concentrated interests harmed by reforms. Reference(s) Alesina, Alberto, Davide Furceri, Jonathan D. Ostry, Chris Papageorgiou and Dennis P. Quinn, 2020. "Structural Reforms and Elections: Evidence from a World-Wide New Dataset," NBER Working Papers 26720, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc. De Haan, Jakob, and Jan-Egbert Sturm. 2017. "Finance and Income Inequality: A Review and New Evidence." European Journal of Political Economy 50: 171–195. Furceri, Davide, and Prakash Loungani. 2018. "The Distributional Effects of Capital Account Liberalization." Journal of Development Economics 130: 127–144. Ostry, Jonathan D., Alessandro Prati, and Antonio Spilimbergo. 2009. "Structural Reforms and Economic Performance in Advanced and Developing Countries." IMF Occasional Paper 268, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. Ostry, Jonathan D., Andrew Berg, and Siddharth Kothari. 2018. "Growth-Equity Trade-offs in Structural Reforms." IMF Working Papers 18/5, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. Prati, Alessandro, Massimiliano G. Onorato, and Chris Papageorgiou. 2013. "Which Reforms Work and Under What Institutional Environment? Evidence from a New Data Set on Structural Reforms." Review of Economics and Statistics 95(3): 946–968. Quinn, Dennis. 1997. "The Correlates of Change in International Financial Regulation." American Political Science Review 91(3): 531–551. Quinn, Dennis P., and A. Maria Toyoda. 2008. "Does Capital Account Liberalization Lead to Growth?" Review of Financial Studies 21(3): 1403–1449. Tweet January 15, 2021 Print Article(s) by this author The political cost of reforms January 15, 2021[Perspectives from Around the World] Articles Column Special Series Newspapers & Magazines Fellows' Works VoxEU Column From IZA Perspectives from Around the World Other Contents RIETI Report Policy Update Keizai Sangyo Journal Communications Newsletter RSS Feed Facebook X YouTube Research Areas Research Programs (FY2024-2028) Research Programs (FY2020-2023) Research Programs (FY2016-2019) Research Programs (FY2011-2015) Policy Research Domains (FY2006-2010) Projects Survey Fellows Research/Policy Papers Discussion Papers (English) Discussion Papers (Japanese) Policy Discussion Papers (English) Policy Discussion Papers (Japanese) Technical Papers (English) Technical Papers (Japanese) Non Technical Summaries List of Articles in Journals Research Digest Discussion Papers Search Publications RIETI Books (English) RIETI Books (Japanese) History of Japan's Trade and Industry Policy Authors' Words Other Publications (English) Other Publications (Japanese) Events Symposiums Workshops BBL Seminars Archived Seminar Series Data JIP Database R-JIP Database CIP Database Industry-Specific Nominal and Real Effective Exchange Rates AMU and AMU Deviation Indicators JSTAR RIETI-TID RIETI FDI Database ICPA Project Links Articles Column Special Series Newspapers & Magazines Fellows' Works VoxEU Column From IZA Perspectives from Around the World Other Contents RIETI Report Policy Update Keizai Sangyo Journal (METI Journal) About RIETI Privacy Policy Site Policy Site Map Help Contact METI Web Site Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry, IAA (JCN 6010005005426)JCN: Japan Corporate Number Opinions expressed or implied on this website are solely those of the author, and do not necessarily represent the views of the Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry (RIETI).Titles, numbers, specific names, etc. on this website are as of the date of publication. In the case of reposting material from our website, contact us beforehand. Top

シャーロットホーネッツ カジノ・レオ公式 業界TOPクラスのオンラインカジノ カジノ・レオ公式 業界TOPクラスのオンラインカジノ ニューカッスルバーン
Copyright ©スコットランドリーグ放送 The Paper All rights reserved.